------------------------------------------------------------------------ (Part 2 of 2) The Asian model Talk of "the Asian financial system" is no doubt too simple. But many countries in East and South-East Asia share enough features to make a simple picture tolerably accurate. Above all, they save a lot compared to western countries, and the savings are done mostly by households. Domestic savings run at roughly twice the American rate, or more than 15 percentage points of GDP higher. Households typically put most of their savings into (low-risk) banks rather than into (higher-risk) equities. Corporate investment is financed in large part by loans from banks. This mechanism has delivered extraordinarily high rates of investment. In America, by contrast, most household savings go to finance households' own investment in housing, and most corporate investment in real productive fixed capital is financed from depreciation and retained profits, with less reliance on bank debt. High levels of corporate debt must be buffered by long-term financial relations between firms and banks, with the government standing ready to support both firms and banks in the event of shocks that affect swathes of the economy all at once (such as sharp rises in interest rates, or sharp falls in demand). If long-term relations did not exist, such shocks would prompt creditors to call their loans and liquidate firms; and where debts are large, the failure of some firms propagates the failure of others much faster than where they are small. This is the financial rationale for what used to be called Asian "alliance capitalism", and has now come to be maligned as "crony capitalism". It is also the rationale of the "convoy" system of Japan, where strong companies support weak ones under various kinds of official encouragement. In some Asian countries, more household savings have been transferred to the enterprise sector through equity markets. Singapore and Malaysia have specialised institutions, such as pension and provident funds financed partly by payroll taxes, which purchase large quantities of equities. In Taiwan both government-and party-directed funds buy equities. However, these are all forms of government-sponsored forced-investment regimes. They share with the debt-transfer systems long-term relationships connecting government, financial sector, and enterprises. In a pure Anglo-American free-market regime, competition and short-term profit maximising make high-debt structures unstable in the face of shocks that interfere with debt-service payments. Creditors seeking to safeguard their assets call in loans and liquidate firms. Bank depositors "run" on banks that might be too exposed to defaults. This collective behaviour causes the whole financial system to shrink, and this spills over into price deflations and depressions. To avoid these outcomes Anglo-American nations long ago agreed that the state had to create a lender of last resort and a body of regulation that placed limits on the indebtedness of private firms, banks and households. These limits of prudent indebtedness were set far below the levels permitted in Asian alliance capitalism. A larger truth Alliance capitalism sounds like an invitation to corruption and insider dealing. The crisis has shown the truth in this allegation, most conspicuously in Indonesia. But there is a larger truth: until the mid-1990s, Asian alliance capitalism generated the highest sustained economic growth for any region in world history. It worked not only as a "catch-up" strategy for countries far from the world technological frontier, but also for Japan as it reached the frontier in the 1980s. To describe it as "a free-market veneer over a state-managed economic structure", which has "inevitably led to the investment excesses and errors to which all similar endeavours seem prone", in the words of senior officials at America's Federal Reserve, misses the point. For a variety of reasons most Asian governments opened their economies to foreign capital in the 1990s. Global banks and portfolio investors flooded in. After 1995 the rise of the dollar and the depreciation of the yen and the yuan led to a loss of export competitiveness in those Asian economies whose currencies were pegged to the dollar. The capital inflows exacerbated the real appreciation of the exchange rates and the loss of export competitiveness, resulting in large, and out-of-character, current-account deficits in Thailand and Malaysia. The inflows also contributed to domestic-asset bubbles, credit excesses, and a growing fringe of bad investments. Foreign investors were providing funds to Asian firms with debt ratios and long-term alliance relationships that would have been unacceptable in the West. When the crisis hit, the violence of the outflow owed much to the realisation that much of the capital should not have been committed in the first place, according to western prudential standards. Enter the IMF When the Fund negotiated its programmes with Thailand, Indonesia and Korea it demanded high real interest rates and fiscal restriction. This was based largely on its experience in Latin America. There, fiscal deficits tended to be large and inflation chronic. Currency devaluations set off hair-trigger inflationary expectations. The cure, quite plausibly, was IMF -style austerity. High real interest rates could be tolerated because corporate debt-to-equity ratios were quite low, because inflation kept eroding the real burden of the debt. In Asia, the Fund failed to see the danger of fiscal restriction where budgets had long been roughly in balance. More seriously, it also failed to see the danger of high real interest rates in economies with high levels of private indebtedness and low inflationary expectations. Under those circumstances, high real interest rates have disastrously deflationary consequences, which give rise to capital outflows regardless of the attractions of high interest rates. Further, the Fund tried to strengthen weakened Asian financial structures by imposing western measures of financial restructuring. Basle rules of capital adequacy were to be applied. Highly indebted banks and firms were to be closed. Labour laws were to be changed to make it easier to fire workers, facilitating the closures. Regulations on foreign ownership were to be lifted in order to allow foreign banks and firms to buy domestic banks and firms. Similar measures were applied in a narrower setting to solve the American savings-and-loan crisis in the late 1980s-and they worked. But it is one thing to undertake such reforms where real interest rates are very low and indebtedness not high (as in America), and another to undertake them where both real interest rates and indebtedness are high. In these conditions the result is closures and lay-offs, with deflationary repercussions and accelerating capital flight. This is why the IMF 's strategy for Asia has failed. The currencies did stop falling in early 1998. But by May deepening contraction, rising unemployment and fear of unrest combined to produce a second wave of capital outflows and renewed falls in currencies and stockmarkets. The second-quarter resumption of the collapse is what finally forced Asian governments to begin to turn away from the initial IMF strategy. They began to cut interest rates and turn fiscal restriction into fiscal expansion. Malaysia slapped on exchange controls in September, the better to engineer an expansion at home without risking further currency falls. South Korea has used government funds to buy out bad loans and finance bank mergers. Japan is seriously discussing nationalising the banks so as to break out of its current trap, in which the attempt to maintain Basle standards of capital adequacy while bank equity falls prevents the needed expansion of credit. Japan is also discussing the reintroduction of exchange controls to allow rapid monetary expansion without depreciating the yen (which might destabilise other currencies in the region and make trade frictions worse). China has suspended the restructuring of state enterprises and banks, because of the deflationary consequences of restructuring in crisis conditions. There is a growing insistence in the region that Asian arrangements have strengths which have been denied in the West-and which need to be built upon to speed recovery. Asia is the world's great savings-surplus region. Its governments' foreign-exchange reserves of almost $800 billion dwarf those of all other regions. Virtually all of these reserves are claims on America (Treasury bills and deposit holdings) and to a lesser degree Europe. The private sectors of Japan, Taiwan and Singapore are also large net lenders to the West. How ironic that a region with such massive savings surplus and net foreign assets should be plunged into crisis by the flight of capital belonging to institutions that reside for the most part in the United States, a massive net debtor with a savings deficit. So try an AMF An Asian Monetary Fund, or AMF , would build on Asia's savings surplus, foreign-exchange reserves, and net-creditor status (including reserves, Treasury bills, and the like). The most severely affected countries-South Korea, Thailand, Malaysia and Indonesia-have gross external debt of perhaps $400 billion, of which over $100 billion has long-term maturities and favourable terms and does not need refinancing. The amount of debt needed to be refinanced in order to stabilize the situation completely is small compared to the aggregate net-creditor position of the region-less than $300 billion. The degree of economic interdependence within Asia that has built up over the past decade means that crisis in one country hurts other Asian countries above all. The all-too-evident neighbourhood contagion effects give each creditor country a strong interest in pooling resources with others in order to avoid further disruption. The AMF would have core financing from subscriptions by member governments. The fact that pledges of $100 billion were quickly secured in August 1997 suggests that sizeable sums would be forthcoming. Additional resources could be tapped by issuing World Bank-type bonds on regional financial markets, guaranteed jointly by the members. The fund would make quick-disbursing loans available to members in difficulty, with conditionalities limited to stabilisation rather than to IMF -type structural reforms. It would operate to reinforce the demonstrated strengths of Asian-type financial systems, and not to disavow them. The AMF would save Asia money. At present the region lends much of its savings to the West at American Treasury bill and deposit rates of 5%, while it borrows from western creditors at 10% or more. With the AMF , Asian lenders would lend at slightly better than 5%, and Asian borrowers would borrow at only slightly more, say 6%. The borrowing governments could repay the more expensive western loans. Asia would then earn the risk premium in the interest rate on emerging Asia's external debt that is now paid over to western creditors. Taking charge of Asias destiny Would Asia not suffer by having western financial markets less involved in resource allocation-as Robert Rubin, America's Treasury secretary, and Alan Greenspan, chairman of the Federal Reserve, have been saying? No. Western financial institutions have failed to discriminate correctly among both sovereign and private borrowers. They piled in to fuel a speculative bubble, and then stampeded out even in the face of high risk premiums, cheap assets, and current-account surpluses. The economic performance of the emerging Asian economies prior to the crisis suggests that Asian governments and their financial institutions can allocate resources more efficiently than that. Isn't an AMF by now redundant? Aren't the current efforts-some bilateral, some involving the existing mutlilateral machinery-quite adequate? No. The existing machinery is based on a "bail-out of basket-cases" myth. The AMF approach says that Asia is unique in having ample financial resources to handle the external financial difficulties of its weakest regional members. It calls on Asians to take charge of their own destiny, and even, in part, to close the door to the West. The threat of closure may even encourage capital flows back to the region, as western bankers try to retain their Asian markets and as portfolio managers, now underweight in Asia, seek to restore their positions and ride the recovery curve. Of course the AMF would compete with the IMF . But the IMF wants competitition for others, and should not be averse to it for itself. The only serious losers would be the western speculators who extract a risk premium they do not deserve. (end of fwd) ------------------------------------------------------------------------ ------------------------------------------------------------------------ a political discussion forum - •••@••.••• To subscribe, send any message to •••@••.••• A public service of Citizens for a Democratic Renaissance (mailto:•••@••.••• http://cyberjournal.org) ---------------------------------------------------------- Non-commercial reposting is hereby approved, but please include the sig up through this paragraph and retain any internal credits and copyright notices. .--------------------------------------------------------- To see the index of the cj archives, send any message to: •••@••.••• To subscribe to our activists list, send any message to: •••@••.••• Help create the Movement for a Democratic Rensaissance ---------------------------------------------- crafted in Ireland by rkm ----------------------------------- A community will evolve only when the people control their means of communication. -- Frantz Fanon
Share: